• 587 days Will The ECB Continue To Hike Rates?
  • 587 days Forbes: Aramco Remains Largest Company In The Middle East
  • 589 days Caltech Scientists Succesfully Beam Back Solar Power From Space
  • 989 days Could Crypto Overtake Traditional Investment?
  • 994 days Americans Still Quitting Jobs At Record Pace
  • 996 days FinTech Startups Tapping VC Money for ‘Immigrant Banking’
  • 999 days Is The Dollar Too Strong?
  • 999 days Big Tech Disappoints Investors on Earnings Calls
  • 1,000 days Fear And Celebration On Twitter as Musk Takes The Reins
  • 1,002 days China Is Quietly Trying To Distance Itself From Russia
  • 1,002 days Tech and Internet Giants’ Earnings In Focus After Netflix’s Stinker
  • 1,006 days Crypto Investors Won Big In 2021
  • 1,006 days The ‘Metaverse’ Economy Could be Worth $13 Trillion By 2030
  • 1,007 days Food Prices Are Skyrocketing As Putin’s War Persists
  • 1,009 days Pentagon Resignations Illustrate Our ‘Commercial’ Defense Dilemma
  • 1,010 days US Banks Shrug off Nearly $15 Billion In Russian Write-Offs
  • 1,013 days Cannabis Stocks in Holding Pattern Despite Positive Momentum
  • 1,014 days Is Musk A Bastion Of Free Speech Or Will His Absolutist Stance Backfire?
  • 1,014 days Two ETFs That Could Hedge Against Extreme Market Volatility
  • 1,016 days Are NFTs About To Take Over Gaming?
  1. Home
  2. Markets
  3. Other

It is not Enough to Tell the Fed to Target Nominal GDP - You Have to Tell it How

In the August 15 edition of the Financial Times, Clive Crook wrote an op-ed piece urging the Fed to target nominal GDP growth. This is not the worst Fed "mandate" that has been recommended. But it is not enough to recommend a mandate or a target to this Fed. You also have to explain to it how to maximize the probability of actually achieving its mandate. Targeting a fed funds rate won't do the trick, especially under current circumstances. I would suggest that if the Fed were to accept Mr. Cook's recommendation of it targeting nominal GDP growth, the Fed should choose as an intermediate target growth in the sum of Federal Reserve, commercial bank, S&L and credit union credit. Chart 1 shows that the correlation between the year-over-year percent change in this credit aggregate and the year-over-year percent change in nominal GDP is 0.61 from Q1:1954 through Q4:2007.

Sum of Federal Reserve, Commercial Bank, S&L and Credit Union Credit

In 2008, there was a significant divergence between the growth in this credit aggregate and the growth in nominal GDP. You may recall that in 2008, the over-the-counter money and capital markets froze up. Businesses, fearing the onset of another depression and with the commercial paper market shut down, tapped their back-up lines of credit at commercial banks quite heavily. The Fed through open the discount window and created new lending facilities to nondepository financial institutions that were desperate for liquidity with the interbank loan market frozen. Thus, this credit aggregate soared. But entities were borrowing not to spend, but rather to be as liquid as possible. Thus, although the sum of Fed, bank, S&L and credit union credit soared in 2008, growth in aggregate spending, as represented by nominal GDP, plunged. Even including this unusual 2008 episode, the correlation between growth in this credit aggregate and growth in nominal GDP remained relatively high at 0.56 (see Chart 2).

Sum of Federal Reserve, Commercial Bank, S&L and Credit Union Credit

I would leave it to the Fed's crack econometric staff to determine how fast the sum of Federal Reserve, commercial bank, S&L and credit union credit should grow in order to hit a nominal GDP growth target. But this is how the Fed could do it. Scrap fed funds rate targeting. Rather, increase or decrease the Fed's balance sheet such that the sum of Fed, commercial bank, S&L and credit union credit grows at the rate that the Fed's econometricians believe is consistent with the Fed's nominal GDP target growth rate.

 

Back to homepage

Leave a comment

Leave a comment