• 526 days Will The ECB Continue To Hike Rates?
  • 526 days Forbes: Aramco Remains Largest Company In The Middle East
  • 528 days Caltech Scientists Succesfully Beam Back Solar Power From Space
  • 928 days Could Crypto Overtake Traditional Investment?
  • 932 days Americans Still Quitting Jobs At Record Pace
  • 934 days FinTech Startups Tapping VC Money for ‘Immigrant Banking’
  • 937 days Is The Dollar Too Strong?
  • 938 days Big Tech Disappoints Investors on Earnings Calls
  • 939 days Fear And Celebration On Twitter as Musk Takes The Reins
  • 940 days China Is Quietly Trying To Distance Itself From Russia
  • 941 days Tech and Internet Giants’ Earnings In Focus After Netflix’s Stinker
  • 945 days Crypto Investors Won Big In 2021
  • 945 days The ‘Metaverse’ Economy Could be Worth $13 Trillion By 2030
  • 946 days Food Prices Are Skyrocketing As Putin’s War Persists
  • 948 days Pentagon Resignations Illustrate Our ‘Commercial’ Defense Dilemma
  • 948 days US Banks Shrug off Nearly $15 Billion In Russian Write-Offs
  • 952 days Cannabis Stocks in Holding Pattern Despite Positive Momentum
  • 952 days Is Musk A Bastion Of Free Speech Or Will His Absolutist Stance Backfire?
  • 953 days Two ETFs That Could Hedge Against Extreme Market Volatility
  • 955 days Are NFTs About To Take Over Gaming?
  1. Home
  2. Markets
  3. Other

News Flash: Economists Clueless

Economist Robert J. Samuelson just published an unintentionally funny article in Capital Journal on the bemusement today's economists feel after being wrong about virtually everything for the past decade.

The end of macro magic
The International Monetary Fund recently held a conference that should concern most people despite its arcane subject - "Rethinking Macro Policy II." Macroeconomics is the study of the entire economy, as opposed to the examination of individual markets ("microeconomics"). The question is how much "macro" policies can produce and protect prosperity. Before the 2008-09 financial crisis, there was great confidence that they could. Now, with 38 million unemployed in Europe and the United States - and recoveries that are feeble or nonexistent - macroeconomics is in disarray and disrepute.

Among economists, there is no consensus on policies. Is "austerity" (government spending cuts and tax increases) self-defeating or the unavoidable response to high budget deficits and debt? Can central banks such as the Federal Reserve or the European Central Bank engineer recovery by holding short-term interest rates near zero and by buying massive amounts of bonds (so-called "quantitative easing")? Or will these policies foster financial speculation, instability and inflation? The public is confused, because economists are divided.

Perhaps the anti-economist backlash has gone too far, as George Akerlof, a Nobel Prize-winning economist, argued. The world, he said, avoided a second Great Depression. "We economists have not done a good job explaining that our macro policies worked," he said. Those policies included: the Fed's support for panic-stricken financial markets; economic "stimulus" packages; the TARP ("Troubled Asset Relief Program"); the auto bailout; "stress tests" for banks; international cooperation to augment demand.

Fair point. Still, the subsequent record is disheartening. The economic models that didn't predict the crisis have also repeatedly overstated the recovery. The tendency is to blame errors on one-time events - say, in 2011, the Japanese tsunami, the Greek bailout and the divisive congressional debate over the debt ceiling. But the larger cause seems to be the models themselves, which reflect spending patterns and behavior by households and businesses since World War II.

"The events [stemming from] the financial crisis were outside the experience of the models and the people running the models," Nigel Gault said in an interview. (Gault, the former chief U.S. economist for the consulting firm IHS, was not at the conference.) The severity of the financial crisis and Great Recession changed behavior. Models based on the past don't do well in the present. Many models assumed that lower interest rates would spur more borrowing. But this wouldn't happen if lenders - reacting to steep losses - tightened credit standards and potential borrowers - already with large loans - were leery of assuming more debt. Which is what occurred.

"We really don't understand what's happening in advanced economies," Lorenzo Bini Smaghi, a former member of the ECB's Executive Board, told the conference. "Monetary policy [policies affecting interest rates and credit conditions] has not been as effective as we thought." Poor economic forecasts confirm this. In April 2012, the IMF predicted that the eurozone (the 17 countries using the euro) would expand by 0.9 percent in 2013; the latest IMF forecast, issued last week, has the eurozone shrinking by 0.3 percent in 2013. For the global economy, the growth forecast for 2013 dropped from 4.1 percent to 3.3 percent over the same period.

Since late 2007, the Fed has pumped more than $2 trillion into the U.S. economy by buying bonds. Economist Allan Meltzer asked: "Why is there such a weak response to such an enormous amount of stimulus, especially monetary stimulus?" The answer, he said, is that the obstacles to faster economic growth are not mainly monetary. Instead, they lie mostly with business decisions to invest and hire; these, he argued, are discouraged by the Obama administration's policies to raise taxes or, through Obamacare's mandate to buy health insurance for workers, to increase the cost of hiring.

There were said to be other "structural" barriers to recovery: the pressure on banks and households to reduce high debt; rigid European labor markets; the need to restore global competitiveness for countries with large trade deficits. But these adjustments and the accompanying policies are often slow-acting and politically controversial.

The irony is rich. With hindsight, excessive faith in macroeconomic policy stoked the financial crisis. Deft shifts in interest rates by central banks seemed to neutralize major economic threats (from the 1987 stock crash to the burst "tech bubble" of 2000). Prolonged prosperity promoted a false sense of security. People - bankers, households, regulators - tolerated more risk and more debt, believing they were insulated from deep slumps.

But now a cycle of over-confidence has given way to a cycle of under-confidence. The trust in macroeconomic magic has shattered. This saps optimism and promotes spending restraint. Scholarly disagreements multiply. Last week, a feud erupted over a paper on government debt by economists Kenneth Rogoff and Carmen Reinhart. The larger lesson is: We have moved into an era of less economic understanding and control.


Some Thoughts

"The economic models that didn't predict the crisis have also repeatedly overstated the recovery. The tendency is to blame errors on one-time events - say, in 2011, the Japanese tsunami, the Greek bailout and the divisive congressional debate over the debt ceiling. But the larger cause seems to be the models themselves, which reflect spending patterns and behavior by households and businesses since World War II." There's a very simple reason why today's Keynesian and Monetarist economists didn't predict the crisis or the anemic recovery. Their models ignore a country's balance sheet, focusing instead on, respectively, "aggregate demand" (i.e. how much stuff we're buying) and the money supply. They assume that as long as these things are rising at a steady pace you'll get healthy growth. But for a country as for a family, how much you spend depends on how much you make and how much you owe.

The one school of economic thought that does focus on macro debt levels is, not coincidentally, the one school that got everything right. The Austrians saw the collapse coming and predicted that record deficits and money printing in the absence of massive debt liquidation would not fix our problems. Today's policies, according to the Austrians, will just make tomorrow's problems a lot worse.

The fact that Austrians see government as a relatively small, unimportant actor in a healthy society makes them repellent to mainstream economists who love the idea of all-powerful government - with themselves running things from behind the curtain. So Austrians have almost no role in major university economics departments. [A personal aside: When GoldMoney's James Turk and I were collaborating on a book a while back we were amused to find that we had both learned economics by watching all the predictions of our Keynesian professors turn out to be dead wrong.]

See here and here for some quotes by Austrian economists Ludwig von Mises and Friedrich Hayek. Compare their clarity and humility to the economists quoted above.

The Reinhart/Rogoff debate, meanwhile, is a perfect illustration of mainstream economists' cluelessness. For those unfamiliar with the story, economists Carmen Reinhart and Ken Rogoff compared past levels of national debt with subsequent economic growth and found that when a government's debt hits 90% of GDP, growth tends to slow to a crawl. This infuriated economists who value debt because of the "flexibility" it confers on governments. And when it was discovered that an Excel error in Reinhart and Rogoff's study accounted for most of their findings, the pro-debt forces declared victory and began calling for an end to austerity everywhere.

All of this is meaningless in any event because Reinhart and Rogoff focused only on government debt and ignored private sector debt. You can't analyze an economy without considering its entire balance sheet. Mortgages and credit cards - and derivatives and unfunded liabilities - are all impediments to growth because by definition they pull future growth into the present. And when you add up all of today's various liabilities you get numbers for most of the developed world approaching 1000% of GDP. Wherever you draw the good/bad dividing line, this much debt is clearly way over in bad territory.

So what's the solution? The Austrians say there's only one: liquidate the bad debt, either through a deflationary crash now or a hyperinflation followed by a deflationary crash later.

Thanks, mainstream economists, for what looks to be an interesting few years.

 

Back to homepage

Leave a comment

Leave a comment