• 314 days Will The ECB Continue To Hike Rates?
  • 314 days Forbes: Aramco Remains Largest Company In The Middle East
  • 316 days Caltech Scientists Succesfully Beam Back Solar Power From Space
  • 716 days Could Crypto Overtake Traditional Investment?
  • 720 days Americans Still Quitting Jobs At Record Pace
  • 722 days FinTech Startups Tapping VC Money for ‘Immigrant Banking’
  • 725 days Is The Dollar Too Strong?
  • 726 days Big Tech Disappoints Investors on Earnings Calls
  • 727 days Fear And Celebration On Twitter as Musk Takes The Reins
  • 728 days China Is Quietly Trying To Distance Itself From Russia
  • 729 days Tech and Internet Giants’ Earnings In Focus After Netflix’s Stinker
  • 733 days Crypto Investors Won Big In 2021
  • 733 days The ‘Metaverse’ Economy Could be Worth $13 Trillion By 2030
  • 734 days Food Prices Are Skyrocketing As Putin’s War Persists
  • 736 days Pentagon Resignations Illustrate Our ‘Commercial’ Defense Dilemma
  • 736 days US Banks Shrug off Nearly $15 Billion In Russian Write-Offs
  • 740 days Cannabis Stocks in Holding Pattern Despite Positive Momentum
  • 740 days Is Musk A Bastion Of Free Speech Or Will His Absolutist Stance Backfire?
  • 741 days Two ETFs That Could Hedge Against Extreme Market Volatility
  • 743 days Are NFTs About To Take Over Gaming?
Zombie Foreclosures On The Rise In The U.S.

Zombie Foreclosures On The Rise In The U.S.

During the quarter there were…

How The Ultra-Wealthy Are Using Art To Dodge Taxes

How The Ultra-Wealthy Are Using Art To Dodge Taxes

More freeports open around the…

The Problem With Modern Monetary Theory

The Problem With Modern Monetary Theory

Modern monetary theory has been…

  1. Home
  2. Markets
  3. Other

Inflation and Human Nature

"...Scrabbling in the earth for a fresh source of cash, the gold & silver miners of 13th century Europe proved that the money supply never simply increases as if by magic..."

YOU MIGHT THINK Ben Bernanke's way with words mere cant, just so much sophistry learnt from the Maestro.

But words matter when we're talking about inflation - or denying it. Choosing the mot juste can prove as crucial as selecting (or denying) the right data.

At the turn of the 20th century, for example, a German scholar, Wilhelm Abel, noticed how medieval chroniclers writing nearly seven centuries earlier had made a curious shift in their choice of words to describe rising grain prices.

Over the three decades between A.D. 1230 and 1260, wheat prices rose by about one quarter in Italy, one-third in France, and nearly as much in England. Writing about these increases year-by-year, Abel found, the chroniclers slowly switched from blaming fames - or shortages and famines - to blaming caristia, a word derived from carus, meaning costly or dear.

The middle of the 13th century, in other words, saw a switch in how people described what was happening to grain prices. The cost of living - as measured by the cost of having enough to eat - was no longer related to good or bad harvests, not according to the chroniclers' choice of words. Instead, the cost of living had become dearer. That changed the way people thought about prices. It also changed the way they responded to rising prices, too.

General price levels kept growing more costly for the next century, in fact, in a phenomena identified by David Hackett Fischer as the Medieval Price Revolution.

"People responded to the discovery of caristia [costliness] by deliberately expanding the quantity of money," writes Hackett Fischer in his tome, The Great Wave (OUP, 1996). "During the thirteenth century, a major effort was made to expand the supply of silver in Europe. Old mines opened again in Hungary...New mines were brought into operation. Output was increased by new technology."

Scrabbling in the earth to uncover fresh supplies of money proved that extra cash didn't simply appear out of thin air, as if by magic. It "was not a deus ex machina," writes Hackett Fischer, "that descended inexorably upon the economy. It was an artifact of human will and purpose."

Put another way, "the most important thing to remember," as Ludwig von Mises reminds us, "is that inflation is not an act of God, that inflation is not a catastrophe of the elements or a disease that comes like the plague. Inflation is a policy."

Who's making policy today? Let's agree that semantics do matter; let's also imagine for a moment that the word "inflation" only describes an increase in the money supply. Then let's bend an ear to the latest choice of words.

"Inflationary pressures have been a feature of the major industrial economies in recent times," said Gordon Brown, the UK finance minister this week.

"Inflation has risen not just in this country but in most of the major countries," said his political partner and rival, Tony Blair - the UK prime minister - earlier this year.

"Inflation rates have been pushed upwards across oil-importing countries," noted José Manuel González-Páramo, an executive of the European Central Bank (ECB) at a seminar in Helsinki last month.

"How should central banks react?" asked the ECB man. And what about the rest of us?

The same pattern that Hackett Fischer found in the Medieval Price Revolution of the 13th century - a pattern of higher price levels preceding a determined attempt to increase the money supply - was also identified in the Price Revolutions of the 16th and then 18th centuries. Steadily rising prices for basic foodstuffs are recorded long before new sources of gold and silver were first tapped.

The Price Revolution of the 16th century, says Hackett Fischer's research, actually began as early as 1480 - "many years before American silver and gold arrived in Europe. In England and Germany, prices nearly doubled during the half century before American silver could have had a significant effect on their economies."

Whatever the initial cause of rising prices - and Hackett Fischer cites population growth in all four of the Price Revolutions he identified between the 13th and 20th centuries - observing the age-old response of human nature to higher prices reveals the true problem of modern central banking. For both the policy wonks themselves and for anyone trying to invest profitably under their fiat money dominion, the natural response to rising prices is actually a search for fresh supplies of cash.

Older, more studied and apparently wiser today, mankind of course knows to meet higher prices with higher interest rates instead. Pace this week's mini-China shock to the Shenzen and global stock markets, tighter reserve ratios are also expected in the commercial banking sector. That should decrease the multiplier effect, or so theory says, thus reducing the availability and growth of credit.

When rising prices become clear in the data, rising interest rates are sure to follow. The supply of money must be restricted, not increased.

But that's not quite what happens.

In the compact and compressed little Price Revolution we've experienced so far in the 21st century, global interest rates slowly began turning higher in late 2003. The Bank of England moved first, followed a year later by the Fed...then the ECB in Frankfurt...and finally the Swiss National Bank and the zero-rate crazy Bank of Japan. Yet the global money supply has by no measure decreased.

The broad supply of Sterling has risen at a double-digit rate annually for the past two years; M3 in the United States is now estimated by John Williams' ShadowStats to be growing at nearly 12% year on year; Eurozone money supply is growing at 10% per year, the fastest rate since 1990.

Let's give the Fed, ECB and Bank of England their heads, and imagine that they actually want rising rates to counter rising prices by restricting money-supply growth. It simply hasn't worked over the last 12 months and more.

Could it be - shhhhhh - that modern central banking is impotent in the face of a genuine and sustained rise in living costs? Are the wonks undone by the rest of us - and most especially the commercial banks - scrabbling in the dirt for fresh supplies of money to overcome the loss of purchasing power that higher prices produce? Or will it take a surprise and shocking increase in interest rates, a hike up to double-digits throughout the industrialized world, to cut money supply growth and so cut the rate of inflation in prices?

"In cultural terms," writes Hackett Fischer of the 13th century gold and silver seekers, "their actions helped individuals and institutions to cope with high prices, but had the collective effect of driving prices higher."

High prices demanded more money; more money led to increased prices. If you ever thought today's rising cost of living would somehow slow down by itself, you failed to account for human nature.

 

Back to homepage

Leave a comment

Leave a comment