• 526 days Will The ECB Continue To Hike Rates?
  • 526 days Forbes: Aramco Remains Largest Company In The Middle East
  • 528 days Caltech Scientists Succesfully Beam Back Solar Power From Space
  • 928 days Could Crypto Overtake Traditional Investment?
  • 933 days Americans Still Quitting Jobs At Record Pace
  • 935 days FinTech Startups Tapping VC Money for ‘Immigrant Banking’
  • 938 days Is The Dollar Too Strong?
  • 938 days Big Tech Disappoints Investors on Earnings Calls
  • 939 days Fear And Celebration On Twitter as Musk Takes The Reins
  • 941 days China Is Quietly Trying To Distance Itself From Russia
  • 941 days Tech and Internet Giants’ Earnings In Focus After Netflix’s Stinker
  • 945 days Crypto Investors Won Big In 2021
  • 945 days The ‘Metaverse’ Economy Could be Worth $13 Trillion By 2030
  • 946 days Food Prices Are Skyrocketing As Putin’s War Persists
  • 948 days Pentagon Resignations Illustrate Our ‘Commercial’ Defense Dilemma
  • 949 days US Banks Shrug off Nearly $15 Billion In Russian Write-Offs
  • 952 days Cannabis Stocks in Holding Pattern Despite Positive Momentum
  • 953 days Is Musk A Bastion Of Free Speech Or Will His Absolutist Stance Backfire?
  • 953 days Two ETFs That Could Hedge Against Extreme Market Volatility
  • 955 days Are NFTs About To Take Over Gaming?
James Bacon

James Bacon

A life-long journalist and writer, James A. Bacon is former Publisher & Editor-in-Chief of Virginia Business magazine, former editor of the Generational Advisor newsletter, and…

Contact Author

  1. Home
  2. Markets
  3. Other

The Skinny on Fiscal Stimulus

Do fiscal stimulus programs work? Do they actually stimulate the economy, or does routing resources through a central government and reallocating it according to political criteria wind up hurting the economy? Converted into economist-speak, the question is this: Do stimulus programs have a positive "fiscal multiplier" -- does $1 in government spending create more than $1 in economic activity -- or a negative one?

Conservative commentators tend to minimize the multiplier, suggesting that government spending tends to be a drag on the economy. Such views just happen to coincide with their philosophical preferences for small government. (I, for one, fall into this category.) Liberal pundits tend to maximize the multiplier. Again, such views reinforce their predilection for bigger, activist government.

Now come three economists -- Ethan Ilzetzki, Enrique G. Mendoza and Carlos A. Vegh -- with a paper, "How Big (Small?) Are Fiscal Multipliers?", published by the National Bureau of Economic Research. Their view: It depends.

The authors argue that previous studies were of limited value because they relied upon annual data, which tends to fudge the time-lag effects of stimulus programs. They have assembled a quarterly dataset for 44 countries (20 high-income and 24 developing) that, they assert, gives a clearer picture.

They find that the impact varies between developed countries and developing countries, between countries whose currencies have exchange rate flexibility as opposed to fixed rates, between countries that conduct a significant amount of foreign trade compared to those that are more closed, and between countries with high outstanding central government debt and those with low debt.

Among their conclusions:

  • Fiscal policy (particularly on the expenditure side) tends to be slow in impacting economic activity, "which raises questions as to the usefulness of discretionary fiscal policy for short-run stabilization purposes." Medium- to long-run effects of increases in government consumption vary considerably.
  • In economies closed to trade or operating under fixed exchange rates, increases in government spending leads to more economic activity. Conversely, countries with open economies and flexible exchange rates show fewer benefits.
  • Fiscal stimulus tends to be counterproductive in highly-indebted countries (in which public debt exceeds 60% of GDP).

Write the authors:

With the increasing importance of international trade in economic activity, and with many economies moving towards greater exchange rate flexibility (typically in the context of inflation targeting regimes), our results suggest that seeking the Holy Grail of fiscal stimulus could be counterproductive, with little benefit in terms of output and potential long-run costs due to larger stocks of public debt. Moreover, fiscal stimuli are likely to become even weaker, and potentially yield even negative multipliers, in the near future, because of the high debt ratios observed in countries, particularly in the industrialized world.

Where does that leave the United States? The authors do not apply their conclusions to specific countries. However, we can easily do so ourselves.

The U.S. economy is one of the most open economies in the world. Although foreign trade does not constitute as large a percentage of the economy as it does in some other countries, the U.S. has very low barriers to entry. It should have come as no surprise, then, when when funds under the American Recovery and Reinvestment Act (better known as the "stimulus" bill) designed to pump up investment in green energy were used to import solar and wind-equipment from China.

Likewise, the U.S. is one of the most highly indebted countries in the world, with a debt-to-GDP ratio well over 60%. While the ARRA stimulus did create new or support existing economic activity in certain areas, the mounting federal debt contributed to fear and uncertainty in the private sector, thus reducing private investment and expansion that would have occurred in the absence of the stimulus. It is impossible, of course, to document investment that "would have happened," but the effect is no less real.

In sum, the logic of Ilzetski, Mendoza and Vegh suggests that fiscal stimuluscould well have a negative multiplier in the U.S., thus doing more harm thangood.

 

Back to homepage

Leave a comment

Leave a comment