• 553 days Will The ECB Continue To Hike Rates?
  • 554 days Forbes: Aramco Remains Largest Company In The Middle East
  • 555 days Caltech Scientists Succesfully Beam Back Solar Power From Space
  • 955 days Could Crypto Overtake Traditional Investment?
  • 960 days Americans Still Quitting Jobs At Record Pace
  • 962 days FinTech Startups Tapping VC Money for ‘Immigrant Banking’
  • 965 days Is The Dollar Too Strong?
  • 965 days Big Tech Disappoints Investors on Earnings Calls
  • 966 days Fear And Celebration On Twitter as Musk Takes The Reins
  • 968 days China Is Quietly Trying To Distance Itself From Russia
  • 968 days Tech and Internet Giants’ Earnings In Focus After Netflix’s Stinker
  • 972 days Crypto Investors Won Big In 2021
  • 972 days The ‘Metaverse’ Economy Could be Worth $13 Trillion By 2030
  • 973 days Food Prices Are Skyrocketing As Putin’s War Persists
  • 975 days Pentagon Resignations Illustrate Our ‘Commercial’ Defense Dilemma
  • 976 days US Banks Shrug off Nearly $15 Billion In Russian Write-Offs
  • 979 days Cannabis Stocks in Holding Pattern Despite Positive Momentum
  • 980 days Is Musk A Bastion Of Free Speech Or Will His Absolutist Stance Backfire?
  • 980 days Two ETFs That Could Hedge Against Extreme Market Volatility
  • 982 days Are NFTs About To Take Over Gaming?
  1. Home
  2. Markets
  3. Other

How Disinflation Could Happen

While the markets are relatively quiet - bond yields rose slightly today and stocks were essentially flat; only commodities were reasonably buoyant - it may be a good time to examine the case for an acceleration of inflation and the risks to that case.

Inflation does not derive from excessive growth, nor deflation from excessive slack. While certain goods and services may experience relative price increases or decreases due to the microeconomic conditions of supply and demand, there aren't any convincing examples of that happening for "aggregate" supply and demand in the absence of accommodating money supply growth. The clearest counterexample to the notion that growth and inflation are intimately interrelated is that in the period just past, the greatest recession in almost a century, year-on-year core inflation never declined, and if we remove the effect of the deflating bubble in housing, core prices in the rest of the economy never increased less than 1.1% on a year-on-year basis (see Chart, Source: Enduring Investments).

Core CPI ex Shelter

Nor is the expansion or contraction of the monetary base the key element in inflation. At one time, when the money multiplier that maps base money into transactional money (e.g., M2) was relatively stable, it didn't matter if one used the monetary base - it was incorrect, but the relationship was stable so it didn't matter. Once the Fed started paying interest on excess reserves, however, the relationship between base money and transactional money was artificially severed and it now matters which aggregate one uses. (See Chart, Source Bloomberg, which shows M2 divided by base money).

M2 Divided By Base Money

When the crisis hit, the velocity of money plunged as commercial bank lending dried up. The Federal Reserve properly countered this drop in velocity by pumping up the raw quantity of money. They did so in an awkward fashion; paying IOER meant the central bank had to add a lot more base money to cause M2 to rise appreciably, but it worked and prices as noted above never declined.

Now, commercial bank credit in the U.S. is expanding again, auguring a turn higher in money velocity in the near future. And yet, the Federal Reserve and other central banks continue to add money, setting up the potential for a long-tail inflation accident if velocity rebounds and the central banks do not begin to tighten in advance of that event. (I find that an extremely unlikely possibility, with Unemployment over 8% in the U.S. and no longer falling, and at least one Fed President calling for unlimited QE!) That doesn't mean that we will get an inflation spike; in fact, year-on-year M2 growth is now under 7% here in the U.S. If money velocity doesn't pick up, then core inflation may only rise slowly from here.

But all of that presumes a closed system where only the U.S. central bank affects the money supply that matters. Unfortunately, or perhaps fortunately, that isn't the case. Inflation is substantially a global phenomenon, and here lies the potential for both optimism and pessimism on inflation.

On the pessimistic side, one must note that even if the Fed does not in fact pursue further QE, other central banks are sure to continue to do so. The Bank of Japan is not about to stop easing when core inflation in that nation remains below zero. The BOE continues to ease and the ECB has little choice but to ease further (or so they believe), and even the relatively responsible RBA is likely to keep money easy with China's slowdown threatening on its doorstep. More money, all else equal, means more global inflation, and more global inflation - unless the U.S. dollar undertakes a serious and extensive appreciation - means more domestic inflation.

But on the optimistic side - for inflation, anyway - European money velocity may be on the verge of collapsing. If you want to make a case for slowing U.S. inflation, I do not believe you can look to the U.S., but rather must look to Europe. If domestic lending (and hence velocity) is rising partly because European lending (and velocity) is contracting, then some of the inflation potential is being sucked out, at least temporarily, by financial and credit strains in Europe.

In my view, the only plausible way we get appreciably lower inflation is if central banks abruptly stop quantitative easing (I don't think there's any measurable chance that they tighten) and the velocity of money in Europe (and Japan) drops faster than the velocity of money in the U.S. rises. In fact, I can make up a deflationary scenario, in which U.S. velocity rolls back over - perhaps because of some unforeseen consequence of the Volcker and conflict-of-interest rules, which some believe may impair securitization markets if the regulators don't clarify certain issues - and central banks actually choose that moment to swear off QE. It's very unlikely - mainly because I don't think central banks will ever do more than pretend to care about inflation, and will keep on adding QE until inflation is not just a danger, but actually high enough that it becomes considered a bigger problem than persistently high unemployment.

However, if I'm wrong, I think the 'optimistic' (in a sense) scenario above is how mild disinflation could come to pass.

 

Back to homepage

Leave a comment

Leave a comment