• 525 days Will The ECB Continue To Hike Rates?
  • 525 days Forbes: Aramco Remains Largest Company In The Middle East
  • 527 days Caltech Scientists Succesfully Beam Back Solar Power From Space
  • 927 days Could Crypto Overtake Traditional Investment?
  • 932 days Americans Still Quitting Jobs At Record Pace
  • 933 days FinTech Startups Tapping VC Money for ‘Immigrant Banking’
  • 937 days Is The Dollar Too Strong?
  • 937 days Big Tech Disappoints Investors on Earnings Calls
  • 938 days Fear And Celebration On Twitter as Musk Takes The Reins
  • 939 days China Is Quietly Trying To Distance Itself From Russia
  • 940 days Tech and Internet Giants’ Earnings In Focus After Netflix’s Stinker
  • 944 days Crypto Investors Won Big In 2021
  • 944 days The ‘Metaverse’ Economy Could be Worth $13 Trillion By 2030
  • 945 days Food Prices Are Skyrocketing As Putin’s War Persists
  • 947 days Pentagon Resignations Illustrate Our ‘Commercial’ Defense Dilemma
  • 948 days US Banks Shrug off Nearly $15 Billion In Russian Write-Offs
  • 951 days Cannabis Stocks in Holding Pattern Despite Positive Momentum
  • 952 days Is Musk A Bastion Of Free Speech Or Will His Absolutist Stance Backfire?
  • 952 days Two ETFs That Could Hedge Against Extreme Market Volatility
  • 954 days Are NFTs About To Take Over Gaming?
Dock Treece

Dock Treece

Dock David Treece is a partner with Treece Investment Advisory Corp (www.TreeceInvestments.com) and is licensed with FINRA through Treece Financial Services Corp. He provides expert…

Contact Author

  1. Home
  2. Markets
  3. Other

Eschewing Efficient Markets

Most columns concerning investments or economics make certain assumptions concerning behavior in and characteristics of markets being discussed. It is taken for granted, for instance, that market participants are behaving in their own self-interest (profit motive), that they are relatively free to act at any given time, that there is minimal government intervention beyond standard rules, regulations, taxes, etc.

Another such assumption typical of columns including this one is that participants (investors) are dealing in what are commonly called efficient markets - markets that do not restrict who can participate or how they act.

In other words, an efficient market should - in theory - represent the sum total knowledge of all participants within that market in real time because each participant is taking certain immediate actions based on their individual expectations with their own self-interest in mind and without restriction.

But what happens when markets aren't efficient?

It's important to first understand that markets are not necessarily efficient. Depending on the market, there may be numerous barriers to entry, or participants may be restricted from taking actions without delay. In many cases, the role government plays in a particular market may be large (e.g. pharmaceuticals), making resources like lobbyists an advantage to certain participants.

Quite often successful investing can be achieved by exploiting such market inefficiencies. While this can be achieved in tradable securities (like those listed on the New York Stock Exchange or comprising the Dow Jones Industrial Average), it's extremely difficult simply because these markets are so large and there are so many participants - some of whom will naturally be more informed.

It can be much easier to find and exploit market efficiencies where they are more obvious. This often occurs in smaller markets, which are naturally less efficient because they have relatively few participants, and/or limited capital flowing in, out, or around.

All this reveals in a very roundabout way that, quite often, investors are very well served by looking for small scale investment opportunities. Such investments can representative tremendous potential for profit because they may not be available to or recognized by other participants, who may be few in number.

The following are examples of people entering what were at the time extremely inefficient markets and finding large-scale profit as those markets gained participants and became more efficient:

  • Bill Gates and Paul Allen entry into the personal computer industry
  • Henry Ford's pioneering of assembly line production for automobiles
  • Joseph P. Kennedy's early involvement in financing the motion picture industry
  • Cornelius Vanderbilt's transition from steamships to railroads
  • Johannes Gutenerg's invention of pass printing (known mostly for the printing of so-called Gutenberg Bibles)
  • Samuel's Colt's innovations in repeating firearms production

Most people don't think of starting their own business in this way, but such ventures are perhaps the best examples of profiteering from inefficient markets. Founders of such enterprises identify a need - a niche - and attempt to come up with a practical, economic solution in a way that also benefits them personally.

Anymore it seems startling how few people ever consider the idea of starting their own business. It seems more and more people, especially from generations X and later, prefer maintaining steady "9 to 5" jobs without ever venturing out on their own.

Our hope - if America is ever to regain the status it once held as an economic superpower - is to see more ordinary citizens hanging out shingles and trusting in their own problem-solving skills. It is only through ingenuity and hard work that American will regain the prestige it once enjoys.

With any luck, changing their perspectives to recognize new ventures as ways to take advantage of inefficient markets - something they'd be hard-pressed to do trading stocks - will encourage more people to do just that.

 

Back to homepage

Leave a comment

Leave a comment