• 556 days Will The ECB Continue To Hike Rates?
  • 556 days Forbes: Aramco Remains Largest Company In The Middle East
  • 558 days Caltech Scientists Succesfully Beam Back Solar Power From Space
  • 958 days Could Crypto Overtake Traditional Investment?
  • 963 days Americans Still Quitting Jobs At Record Pace
  • 965 days FinTech Startups Tapping VC Money for ‘Immigrant Banking’
  • 968 days Is The Dollar Too Strong?
  • 968 days Big Tech Disappoints Investors on Earnings Calls
  • 969 days Fear And Celebration On Twitter as Musk Takes The Reins
  • 971 days China Is Quietly Trying To Distance Itself From Russia
  • 971 days Tech and Internet Giants’ Earnings In Focus After Netflix’s Stinker
  • 975 days Crypto Investors Won Big In 2021
  • 975 days The ‘Metaverse’ Economy Could be Worth $13 Trillion By 2030
  • 976 days Food Prices Are Skyrocketing As Putin’s War Persists
  • 978 days Pentagon Resignations Illustrate Our ‘Commercial’ Defense Dilemma
  • 979 days US Banks Shrug off Nearly $15 Billion In Russian Write-Offs
  • 982 days Cannabis Stocks in Holding Pattern Despite Positive Momentum
  • 983 days Is Musk A Bastion Of Free Speech Or Will His Absolutist Stance Backfire?
  • 983 days Two ETFs That Could Hedge Against Extreme Market Volatility
  • 985 days Are NFTs About To Take Over Gaming?
  1. Home
  2. Markets
  3. Other

How the Fed's Price Rule Triggers Recessions

Economic commentary is in a very poor state. Every change in the unemployment figures, consumer spending, the deficit, output, etc., is examined in the same way a fortune teller examines tealeaves, and with the same dismal results. What matters is analysis and not statistics.

Without the proper analytical tools these statistics are largely meaningless. The Fed's interest rate decisions are something that constantly exercises the minds of our economic commentariat. Will Bernanke raise them? Will he lower them? Will he keep them steady? Despite this speculative questioning the problem of meddling with interest rates is the one question that never arises.

It is taken as given that manipulating interest rates is a vital function of every central bank. At this very instant some commentators are arguing for further increases in rates to head off inflationary pressures. Others express caution, fearing that if rates are raised too much the economic growth will be killed off and the economy will slide into recession.

The thought that there is a connection between the manipulation of rates and the so-called boom-and-bust cycle is rarely given any consideration in the US media. (The Australian media is every bit as bad). Once we start to focus on rates and economic stability our attention should be drawn to the price rule, a rule that many commentators congratulated Greenspan on successfully adhering to and which, in their opinion, explains the economic success of the Clinton years.

According to this rule inflation is defined as too much money chasing too few goods. Therefore, if the Fed uses interest rates to match the money supply with output this will stabilise prices and remove the threat of recession. This theory treats minor rises in the CPI of 2 per cent or so as of little importance. It follows from the rule that falling prices are defined as too little money chasing too many goods and that this situation is dangerously deflationary.

This fear springs from the misguided belief that falling prices always squeeze profit margins and so depress economic activity. But the rule is based on a total misconception of the nature of inflation and deflation, and has become a dangerous recipe for economic instability.

The 1920s boom provides an enduring example of the damage the price rule can inflict on an economy. While qualitative economists like Benjamin M. Anderson and members of the Austrian School warned that the 'stable' price level was concealing a dangerous boom that would result in a depression, the likes of Fisher, Sir Ralph Hawtrey and Keynes interpreted this so-called stability as evidence that the economy was stable.

Dissenters tried to bring to public attention the fact that these so-called stable prices were concealing enormous imbalances that were being generated by excess credit, and that these imbalances would eventually have to be liquidated once the economy went into an unavoidable recession.

The same thing happened during the 1990s. In other words, failure to see that a comparatively stable price level can hide accumulating distortions led many to believe that the economy had entered a "new economic era", one that had permanently banished the business cycle.

It is truly ironic that though the qualitative economists of the 1920s were vindicated by subsequent events their Cassandra-like warnings were virtually lost to history while the free market got the blame for the Great Depression, just as it will get the blame for next recession.

Back to homepage

Leave a comment

Leave a comment