• 524 days Will The ECB Continue To Hike Rates?
  • 524 days Forbes: Aramco Remains Largest Company In The Middle East
  • 526 days Caltech Scientists Succesfully Beam Back Solar Power From Space
  • 926 days Could Crypto Overtake Traditional Investment?
  • 930 days Americans Still Quitting Jobs At Record Pace
  • 932 days FinTech Startups Tapping VC Money for ‘Immigrant Banking’
  • 935 days Is The Dollar Too Strong?
  • 936 days Big Tech Disappoints Investors on Earnings Calls
  • 937 days Fear And Celebration On Twitter as Musk Takes The Reins
  • 938 days China Is Quietly Trying To Distance Itself From Russia
  • 939 days Tech and Internet Giants’ Earnings In Focus After Netflix’s Stinker
  • 942 days Crypto Investors Won Big In 2021
  • 943 days The ‘Metaverse’ Economy Could be Worth $13 Trillion By 2030
  • 944 days Food Prices Are Skyrocketing As Putin’s War Persists
  • 946 days Pentagon Resignations Illustrate Our ‘Commercial’ Defense Dilemma
  • 946 days US Banks Shrug off Nearly $15 Billion In Russian Write-Offs
  • 949 days Cannabis Stocks in Holding Pattern Despite Positive Momentum
  • 950 days Is Musk A Bastion Of Free Speech Or Will His Absolutist Stance Backfire?
  • 950 days Two ETFs That Could Hedge Against Extreme Market Volatility
  • 952 days Are NFTs About To Take Over Gaming?
  1. Home
  2. Markets
  3. Other

The Post Budget Debate

Press comment on the budget has been sharply divided. Most writers have been scornful of the Chancellor's economic forecasts, while a few believe that he will be vindicated. The key feature of both views is their naivety. With regrettably few exceptions, neither opponents nor supporters have yet twigged the essential folly of Gordon Brown's whole approach.

The Chancellor wants attention to be focussed on the cyclically-adjusted budget deficit rather than its current level and the press have been silly enough to oblige him. From a political view this has great advantages. It confuses the issue and distracts attention from his forecasting failures.

From the viewpoint of economic management, however, it has many faults. There are three key problems in the Chancellor's approach. First, we don't know where we are in the cycle. Second, we don't know the trend growth rate of the economy. Third, tax revenue with unchanged tax rates is subject to structural as well as cyclical fluctuations.

In current circumstances, ignoring these points leads the defenders of Gordon Brown even more astray than his detractors. For example, one of the former has written that "If we believe that Britain's trend growth rate is between 2.25 and 2.75%, (as almost all economists believe), then a period of sub-par growth such as 2000 to 2002 must be followed by a period of unsustainably rapid expansion. It is a matter of simple arithmetic."

This is nonsense. First, output could have been above trend and merely fallen back into line over the past two years. Secondly, the trend could have moved downwards because of the poor growth in productivity, to which, as I pointed out last week, the Chancellor has been a major contributor.

Economists are almost universally scornful of the idea that we can know where we are in the cycle. A recent paper by Anthanasios Orphanides and Simon van Norden underlined this in stark terms.

Another problem illustrated by quotation lies in the implicit assumption that it makes no great difference to budget planning if the trend growth rate of the economy is 2.25% or 2.75%. Unfortunately it is very important, as the resulting error becomes increasingly serious over time. If the trend growth rate of the economy is over-estimated by 0.5% p.a., the resulting loss of revenue will increase the budget deficit by 0.2% p.a.

If tax planning, both for the past three years and looking forward, is based on such a misjudgement, then this feature alone will produce a tax revenue shortfall of 1% of GDP two years out.

The practical issue is not whether the Chancellor has got his sums wrong, which he clearly has, but whether this is bad for the UK economy. The world today needs every stimulus that it can get, so it could be argued that Gordon Brown's imprudence is Britain's good fortune.

In fact this is unlikely to be true. Had the Chancellor's past budgets been prudent in fact rather than in spin, the Bank of England's monetary policy would have been more accommodating. This could have made the housing bubble even worse, but, since interest rates are low by historic standards, it is more likely that the major benefit would have been through a lower exchange rate.

Had the UK economy been managed better, sterling would be lower and investment higher. Both of which would greatly benefit our long-term growth prospects. We would also have the ability, which is now almost certainly lacking, of using fiscal policy to boost the economy should the world fall into serious deflation.

Back to homepage

Leave a comment

Leave a comment